A History of
Feudalism in Scotland
It
was Sir Thomas Innes of Learney, a former Lord Lyon King
of Arms, who wrote in the volume, 'Scots Heraldry' that:
'Scotland,
owing to its clan organisation, has enjoyed a complete
absence of class distinctions or 'class consciousness',
and a corresponding popularity – indeed whole-hearted
veneration – for everything pertaining to rank and
lineage, honours, dignities and ensigns armorial.'
In the broader context it is important to understand
that feudalism in Scotland was not imposed on a
conquered people, as happened in England after the
Norman Conquest, it was introduced in a well-developed
form in a piecemeal and more or less peaceable fashion
by the Kings of Scots themselves. Although the majority
of those at the top of the feudal pyramid were either
Anglo-Norman, Breton or Fleming incomers (the families
of Balliol, Bruce and Stewart among them), there was not
the bitter hatred between conqueror (Normans) and
conquered (Saxons) that was such a notable factor in
England. Not only that but the introduction of feudalism
in Scotland tended to reinforce the bonds of mutual
loyalty and protection that already existed under the
clan system and feudal institutions, to a large extent,
merely replaced similar institutions that were already
there. The ancient earldoms continued to exist but were
converted into feudal holdings from the Crown and the
pre-feudal thanages were gradually replaced by baronies.
In fact the introduction of feudalism did little to
alter the view of the clansmen, which persisted into the
late nineteenth century, and which still probably finds
some sympathy in the heart of every modern Scot, that
clan lands belong to the clan.
Feudalism originated as a system by which land was held
in return for military service. The feudal relationship
was a mutual obligation (an honourable bond) between two
free parties, the superior and the vassal. The 'feudal
agreement' proper, soon superseded by a written charter,
consisted of two parts, an act of homage by the vassal,
in which the vassal would place his hands between those
of his superior and swear fealty to him, and an act of
investiture by the superior granting land to the vassal
to be held of the superior. This ceremony was conducted
in front of reputable witnesses. The act of investiture
involved the handing over of a sod of earth and a stone
and once a vassal was 'infeft' in this manner he was
described as being 'seized' of his lands, which he was
in a literal sense. The principal obligation of the
vassal was military service but this was later replaced
by a money payment or nominal consideration (a penny, a
rose, a glove, a blast of a hunting horn etc.) called
'blench ferm'.
In addition to owing military allegiance to his
superior, the vassal also attended (owed suit to) his
superior's court, which all superiors were entitled to
hold for the administration and regulation of their
lands. In return the superior undertook to provide
protection and justice (in his court). There were
penalties for non-compliance and, critically, either
side could repudiate the feudal agreement if the other
party did not meet their obligations or abused their
position; this happened most notably when the Magna
Carta barons repudiated their allegiance to King John,
who demanded unconstitutional feudal 'aids', effectively
illegal taxes, amongst other, less mentionable,
misdemeanours.
It appears that in the very early days of feudalism
there was no automatic right to succession by a vassal's
heir but, over time, the feudal agreement became
hereditary on both sides, that is between the superior
and his heirs and the vassal and his heirs, and this
gave the vassal relative security of tenure. When a
vassal succeeded 'relief' was normally payable to the
superior (£100 was the standard relief for a barony in
England) and, if a minor succeeded, the superior
normally had the right of wardship of that minor, hence
the term 'ward holding' used to describe the most common
form of early feudal tenure. If the minor was a girl
this effectively included the right to marry her off to
the highest bidder, an important source of revenue.
Since the minor was clearly incapable of providing the
military service due from the lands, the superior
required to be compensated and wardship gave the
superior control of the lands and their revenues.
A
vassal who received a feu of lands in this manner could
sub-feu all or part of those lands to others, who might
also sub-feu, and feudal society was therefore
hierarchical, a social pyramid. At the top of the
hierarchy was the King, who as 'paramount superior'
owned all the land (though whether he could control it
was another matter) and was the fountain of honour and
justice. Everyone was part of this hierarchy, and
therefore subject to the feudal system and its laws. The
exception was outlaws, who were literally 'outside the
law' (hence the name) and, having no legal protection,
could be killed with impunity. The feudal system was, in
this sense, a great equaliser since it bound everyone,
from the highest to the lowest, within the same legal
framework. As Professor Barrow states ('Kingship and
Unity, Scotland, 1000-1306', p. 43) 'in the process [of
feudalisation] the highest was inevitably brought a
little lower and the lowest somewhat raised'.
Below the King were his immediate vassals, his
tenants-in-chief or 'barons', derived from the Latin
baro meaning 'servant' or 'man'. Thus the King's barons
were, in a sense, simply the 'King's men', just as the
vassals of any superior were that superior's 'men' or,
in a sense, his 'barons'. In the same sense all the
immediate vassals of any superior were peers of each
other, although the term came ultimately to be
restricted to 'Peers of the Realm', that is those who
had a right to a seat and vote in the House of Lords.
The 'baronage' consisted of the earls and barons (the
titles of Duke, Marquess and Viscount arrived in
Scotland somewhat later, in 1398, 1599 and 1606
respectively), both of whom held their lands 'by
barony', that is per baroniam.
Earldoms and baronies were territorial as opposed to
personal dignities and were therefore attached to the
land rather than the individual, unlike modern peerages.
Lands were erected into an earldom or barony and those
lands were then granted out by the King. Both of these
steps were effected by a single charter under the Great
Seal. A man became a baron by virtue of being granted a
barony, a baron by tenure, he was not personally made a
baron. If an earl or baron disposed of his lands, which
in theory he could only do with the consent of the King
by means of resignation (to the King) and re-grant (by
the King), the title went with the lands. Earls and
barons were therefore noble because they held noble
fiefs, that is lands that conferred nobility, as opposed
to ignoble fiefs, lands that did not confer nobility
(Lord Bankton, 'An Institute of the Laws of Scotland',
II, III, para. 83). However, it seems that, in Scotland
at least, if not also elsewhere, all armigers (those who
had a coat of arms) were considered noble and that the
distinction between nobles and non-nobles was between
those who were 'known' (nobilis) by virtue of having a
coat of arms and those who did not have a coat of arms
and were therefore 'unknown' (ignobilis). Indeed, a
modern grant of arms from the Lord Lyon, for which
anyone of Scottish ancestry can apply, will state that
the grantee is 'amongst all Nobles and in all Places of
Honour, to be taken, numbered, accounted and received as
a Noble in the Noblesse of Scotland'. It seems that
under Scots law arms are also a noble fief conferring
nobility (Sir Thomas Innes of Learney, 'Scots Heraldry',
p.83). This view is supported by the following extract
quoted in 'Ancient Heraldic Tracts' by Sir James
Balfour, (p. 9): 'Aptlie a prince is said to nobilitat
one quhen, ather by expresse wordes or by wreat, or
other wayes by some externall acte or ceremoney, he
manifests his princely magnificence and creatione,
aither by giuing of Armes or Signe Armorialls to be
borne by the party so honoured in Escutcheons, ore by
careing Helmetts with open Beuer, muche ussed by the
Germans. Gutier, lib. 3. et 4. quest. 17. num 151.
Petrus Gregorius, lib. 6. de Repub. cap. 16. num. 2.'
As the King's immediate vassals the earls and barons
owed suit to the King's court, which remained the
supreme court of law after it had evolved into what we
now call Parliament. The earls and barons, who
constituted the nobility, attended Parliament along with
representatives of the Church and the Burghs (towns) and
these three together (Nobility, Prelates and Burgesses)
came to be referred to as the 'Community of the Realm'.
For the sake of completeness it is worth noting that
there were, and still are, baronies held of earls (and
also the Lord of the Isles until 1494). These were
essentially a hangover from the pre-feudal period when
the 'Seven Earls' (of Atholl, Fife, Moray, Mar,
Strathearn, Caithness and Angus) were princes, if not
kings (Righ), in their own territories and the King of
Scots was 'High King' (Ard-Righ). Most of these baronies
were later converted into baronies held of the King.
Although both earls and barons held their lands 'by
barony' and sat in Parliament by virtue of being barons,
there was always a distinction between the two, for the
earls effectively retained their function as provincial
governors, sat apart in Parliament on the steps of the
throne and wore distinctive robes of office. Over time,
the earls and more important barons (barones majores)
were distinguished from the lesser barons (barones
minores), who might hold only a few hundred acres and
for whom the business of attending parliament was costly
and inconvenient. The lesser barons continued to hold
territorial dignities but a new peerage by patent, as
opposed to baronage by tenure, evolved from the granting
of personal dignities, mainly to the holders of existing
earldoms and baronies in the first instance. The
earliest of these was the Earldom of Douglas granted to
William Douglas in 1358. These personal dignities were
not attached to land (a cheapskate form of patronage!)
and descended in accordance with the destination
specified in the patent of creation, usually heirs male
of the grantee. This gave rise to situations where a
feudal title and a personal title of the same name, such
as the Earldom of Arran, were held by one person.
By an Act of 1428 (A.P.S., ii, 15) the minor barons and
freeholders were excused from attending Parliament and
were allowed to send two or more commissioners from each
shire ('twa or ma wismen efter the largeness of the
schrefdome') to represent them. This Act does not seem
to have been implemented because it was only following a
petition to Parliament in December 1585 requesting that
the minor barons and freeholders should be represented
that a further Act was passed in 1587 (A.P.S., iii, 509,
c. 120) by which 'the said act [of 1428] maid be king
James the first to tak full effect and executioun'. It
was in this manner that the Shire representatives in the
Scottish Parliament, which still sat as a single body,
evolved (together with the Burgh representatives) into
the equivalent of the English House of Commons.
In addition to being tenants-in-chief of the King (and
having the rights and duties this implied), barons had a
second function concerned with the administration of the
judicial system. These were two sides of the same coin
of course; as a vassal of the King a baron was obliged
to attend the King's court, as a superior the baron was
obliged to hold courts for his immediate vassals. These
two functions became the critical features by which the
baron could be identified - his position as
tenant-in-chief of the King and his 'baronial
jurisdiction'. As Sir John Skene stated in 1597 in his
celebrated glossary of Scots legal terms "In this Realme
he is called ane Barrone quha haldis his landes
immediatlie in chiefe of the King and hes power of pit
and gallows". In the early period charters were explicit
in enumerating baronial rights (cum sacca et socca,
tholl et them, et infangthief, cum furca et fossa –
Charter of the Barony of Seton, 1169) but over time
charters erecting baronies came to use a standard
phraseology and baronial rights were encompassed by the
single phrase in liberam baroniam – 'in free barony'.
The administration of public justice in rural medieval
Scotland was carried out largely by the baronial courts,
from which there was a right of appeal in civil cases to
the local Sheriff Court and which were subject to
supervision by the local Sheriff Court in criminal
matters. As Alexander Grant states ('Independence and
Nationhood, Scotland 1306-1469', p. 151) barons '
presided over most of the ordinary government and
justice experienced by most of the people of Scotland'.
Baronies have been properly described as 'franchise
jurisdictions' and they worked in principle like any
modern franchise; that is, the baron exercised a limited
legal jurisdiction in a specified area (the barony) and,
in return, was allowed to retain the profits of the
office, that is the fines. It was the private
administration of a part of public justice. It is
important to understand that the baron was responsible
only for the administration of justice within the
barony, he did not act as judge or jury (these functions
were carried out by the baron's vassals, his tenants)
and although, like any system, feudalism was open to
abuse, the principle that a man should not be a judge in
his own cause (aliquis non debet esse judex in propria
causa) was of the essence. As Professor William Croft
Dickinson states ('The Court Book of the Barony of
Carnwath 1523-1542', p. lxxx) 'the baron was technically
in the same position as any other litigant', which meant
that in a dispute between the baron and one of his
tenants, it was the not the baron who decided the
outcome but his other tenants. Where this principle was
not observed, as happened in the later feudal period,
this constituted an abuse of the feudal system, not a
feature of it.
The jurisdiction of the baronial courts was strictly
limited. The popular image of barons exercising at their
own whim the 'power of life and limb' over their vassals
is a distortion. While baronial jurisdiction certainly
included 'furca et fossa' – the power of pit (fossa –
the right to drown women) and gallows (furca – the right
to hang men) – this power was limited to theft and
manslaughter (un-premeditated killing) only and even
then the criminal had to be caught within the barony
either in possession of the stolen goods or
'red-handed'. More serious crimes, notably murder, rape,
arson and robbery (the Four Pleas of the Crown) were
dealt with by the itinerant Justiciars, who were senior
royal officials, or by the regality court if the barony
was within a regality (for which see below). The right
to try cases of treason was always reserved to the
Crown. In fact, the business of the baron courts was
mainly concerned, as one would expect, with the
day-to-day administration of a rural estate (the barony)
and included such matters as settling boundary disputes
between neighbours, determining compensation for damage
caused by cattle, organising the repair of the barony
mill and so on. A baron court might ordain that 'non
within the Barony and Jurisdiction drink excessively nor
be sensibly drunke nor known to be drunk nor use filthy
nor scurlus speeches and that non mock at piety' (Stitchill,
4) or might appoint men as 'haiffand power of the laird
to tak ordour with all flytters and bakbytters as they
find the fault, and to be put in the stocs quhill
peyment be maid of fourtie sh.' (Spalding Club Misc., v.
224). The baron court is therefore probably best
regarded as an administrative council of the baron and
his tenants (a sort of parliament in fact), as well as a
court of law, and might not try a juicy manslaughter
case for decades, if ever – which was probably a bit of
a disappointment for the tenants – and from the
sixteenth and seventeenth centuries onwards the trying
of capital crimes in the baron courts fell into
desuetude, until finally abolished by the Heritable
Jurisdictions Act of 1747. In fact, as far as possible,
people tried to avoid resorting to the courts at all and
disputes were often settled by informal negotiation
under the auspices of respected neighbours (called 'burlaw
men'). As Alexander Grant states ('Independence and
Nationhood, Scotland 1306-1469', p. 156) 'the most
striking aspect of medieval Scotland's legal system is
probably the role of the people, in practice they seem
generally to have dispensed their justice themselves'.
The lynch-pin of the barony was the baronial castle or
manor which, as the 'caput' or head of the barony, was a
public place and the source of justice for the community
in peacetime (i.e. where the courts were held) and of
its protection in times of war or civil disorder. Their
function is neatly summarised in a statute of James I (APS,
ii. 13, c. 7) which ordered all lords beyond the Mounth
to build, repair and reconstruct 'thar castellis and
maneris and duell in thaim be thaim self or be ane of
thare frendis for the gracious gouernall of their landis
be gude polising'. It was only in unsettled times and
particularly when royal authority was weak that, in
certain limited cases, the baronial castle can be
rightly seen as a source of anarchy or oppression.
We also need to be aware of regalities, which were a
form a barony with higher jurisdictional powers and
other privileges and which were erected in liberam
regalitatem as opposed to in liberam baroniam. They were
equivalent to the Palatine Counties in England, such as
Durham (still called 'The County Palatine of Durham'),
Lancashire and Cheshire, or Palatinates on the
Continent, such as the Palatinate of the Rhine. A
lordship of regality was a royal dignity and 'Lords of
Regality' had, as the title implies, regal powers,
including complete criminal jurisdiction (excluding only
treason), as well as their own chancery and mint and
were effectively reguli or little kings within their
domains. Civil appeals from regality courts went only to
Parliament. Royal officers, including Justiciars and
Sheriffs, had no authority in a regality and thus the
kingdom was divided into royalty and regality (Lord
Bankton, 'An Institute of the Laws of Scotland', II,
III, para. 83). To hold land in regality was a major
status symbol (and a source of significant additional
revenue) and grants of regality were normally restricted
to members of the royal family and leading magnates.
Regalities included the Earldoms of Moray, Atholl,
Strathearn and March, the Lordships of Badenoch, Garioch,
Renfrew and Carrick, lands of the Earls of Douglas, the
Earls of Angus, of the Douglas family of Dalkeith and a
number of baronies ('Atlas of Scottish History to 1707',
p. 207). Since a regality would normally be erected over
an existing earldom or a number of existing baronies,
such an erection would have little impact on the
administration of justice within the regality; the
existing courts would have continued to function very
much as before. The only practical difference would have
been that more serious crimes (murder, rape, arson and
robbery) would have been tried in the Regality Court
rather than by the relevant Justiciar (of the North or
South as the case might be), which quite probably
speeded the process up, and that civil appeals from the
Baron Court would have gone to the Regality Court rather
than the Sheriff Court. It should be noted that erection
of a feudal earldom or lordship implied no higher
jurisdictional rights than an ordinary barony, unless
that earldom or lordship was also erected into a
regality. The caput or head of a regality was
technically a palatium, that is a palace (Alexander
Nisbet, 'A System of Heraldry', Vol. 2, Part 4, p. 46).
Regalities probably had little effect on the day to day
life of ordinary people, unless perhaps your local Lord
of Regality happened to be Alexander Stewart, 'Wolf of
Badenoch'! Even so, regalities remained subject to royal
authority and on those occasions when Lords of Regality
came into conflict with the Crown they were resoundingly
crushed, as happened to the eighth and ninth Earls of
Douglas.
In feudal theory a barony would be held of the King for
a number of knights' fees, say 10, 20, 30 or more (the
number varied according to the size of the barony,
although there was no standard area of land defined as a
'knight's fee'), which meant that, when summoned by the
King to do so, the baron was obliged to supply the
specified number of knights to fight in the King's army
for the standard period of service, normally 40 days. In
order to meet this military obligation the baron would
normally 'feu' (grant in fee) part of his lands to
others, milites or knights, who held of him by one or
more knights' fees or even a fraction of a knight's fee.
Part of the levy might be met by household knights, that
is knights who were part of the baron's household
retinue and who did not hold land by knight's service.
Knight's service was the lynchpin of the feudal system,
since it was by this mechanism that the system of
holding of land in return for military service operated.
In England feudalism certainly operated on this model,
that is knights holding of barons. There was a large
knightly class which it is recognised later formed the
basis of the landed gentry or squirearchy and the House
of Commons. In Scotland, while knights certainly
existed, the knightly class seems to have been less
evident (partly no doubt as a result of the relative
poverty of the country and scarcity of good land) and
their equivalent in Scotland seems to have been the
minor barons, clan chiefs, lairds and so on, who were
less vociferous than their English equivalent and less
conscious of their identity as a class. This, along with
the fact that the minor barons continued to sit, or at
least have the right to sit, in Parliament as nobles
(which right knights did not have of course) is the
reason why no House of Commons evolved in Scotland. An
interesting result of these different models of
feudalism, if we can call them that, was that England
could field a large and well-equipped army via the
feudal levy (there were more than 2,000 English knights
at Bannockburn) whereas Scotland could only hope to
match its larger and richer neighbour by what was
effectively a national mobilisation, a levée en masse.
Even so the number of knights that Scotland could put
into the field was always small and a Scottish feudal
army consisted of what were effectively the armies of
the Earls (harking back the their pre-feudal role) and
the barons with their tenantry (and God help an English
knight if they got hold of him!).
Below knights were the yeomen, that is free peasants
(called 'husbandmen' in Scotland), so-called because
they were not tied to the land in the same manner as
serfs or villeins, that is unfree peasants (called 'neyfs'
in Scotland). It appears that in the early feudal period
the land was worked mainly by unfree peasants (neyfs)
and it was only later, with the gradual disappearance of
neyfship in the 14th century, that an identifiable class
of richer peasants, the husbandmen, emerged. Below them
were a class of 'cottars' or very small scale farmers,
often sub-tenants of husbandmen. Below both of these
were landless labourers who, though the evidence is
scanty, may have formed as much as one third of the
population of adult males. The majority of the peasant
population held their land on short, usually annual,
leases and it is here, the distinction between those who
enjoyed security of tenure and those who did not, that
perhaps the key social divide within the feudal system
lies. Short leases were clearly devised to benefit the
landlord but, even so, we must remember that in times of
population decline, and hence reducing rents, short
leases benefited the tenants.
The distinction between these two classes of peasant was
greater than the distinction between the substantial
husbandmen and the lower ranks of the nobility, for a
substantial husbandman might farm a larger area than a
small baron (Alexander Grant, 'Independence and
Nationhood, Scotland 1306-1469', p. 122) and his family
could even, over time, join the ranks of the nobility.
As Grant states (p. 121) 'Although late-medieval
Scottish society was not totally fluid, class
consciousness was probably relatively slight, while
upward social mobility, depending on the acquisition of
freeholdings and open to anyone with sufficient wealth,
would have been fairly straightforward. The only real
social barriers seem to have been economic ones.' We
must also remember the rate at which noble families
became extinct and although the Scottish nobility seems
to have survived better than the nobility in England and
France, where an extinction rate of 25% of noble
families every generation was about the norm, a constant
supply of 'new blood' was both required and forthcoming.
Not only was movement possible up the social ladder (and
of course even the most noble of families originally
rose from humble stock, though you might not get this
impression from their pedigrees!) but movement down the
social ladder was also a constant process. Many nobles
had numerous progeny and they could not all be provided
with landed estates, so the younger sons of baronial or
chiefly families would often go into the professions or
trade (to which there appears to have been less stigma
attached than in England) and daughters would often
marry lower down the social ladder. Over time their
descendants might move further down the social ladder
and this is the reason why if you walk down the High
Street of any Scottish town you will see shop signs
which say, for example, R. Bruce (Butcher), J. Stewart
(Baker) and W. Hamilton (Candlestick Maker), though we
must not forget that (frustratingly!) many a bearer of a
famous Scottish name is descended from someone who
simply assumed the name of their lord or clan chief.
As far as the neyfs are concerned, we need to remember,
firstly, that neyfship disappeared from Scotland at a
relatively early date (by 1370 or thereabouts) and,
secondly, that, as Professor Barrow states ('Kingship
and Unity, Scotland, 1000-1306', p. 18) 'in practice the
extent of their servitude would have been lessened by
two things, first by the comparatively high degree of
personal freedom conferred by the pastoral way of life
(men whose wealth is on the hoof can more easily take
refuge from oppression than men who depend on harvesting
field crops) and secondly by the markedly vertical
structure of Scottish society. This meant that in every
shire and region what counted was the lineage and
kindred to which a man or woman belonged. Freedom was
neither absolute nor homogeneous, but was experienced
and enjoyed at different levels in different milieux'.
In addition Professor Barrow draws our attention (page
19) to a charter of William the Lion in which he refers
to his thanes of Birse in Aberdeenshire as his 'neyfs'.
He goes on to say 'our modern notions of an unbridgeable
gulf between a free and privileged aristocracy on the
one hand and an oppressed peasantry on the other cannot
be squared easily with the concepts actually prevailing
in the twelfth century. In any case we should do well to
recall the underlying harshness of life in our period.
The absence of legal freedom would often have seemed a
small enough matter when set beside the threat of
harvest failure or epidemic disease among the livestock
upon which the very survival of a peasant family
depended.'
It seems to be clear, on this basis, that our notion of
feudalism in Scotland might require revision. The
nobility had rather less unbridled power and there was
less differentiation and more mobility between the lower
ranks of the nobility and the higher ranks of the
peasantry, in both directions, than we might have
thought. The bonds of servitude of the neyfs appear to
have been stronger in concept than in practice and their
servitude seems to have been of relatively small moment
when put in the context of the harshness of life at the
time.
Considering the evidence presented here as a whole it
would seem that there is a large element of truth in Sir
Thomas Innes of Learney's statement ('Scots Heraldry',
p. 3) that 'the chieftain's turreted keep with its
carved escutcheons and emblazoned banner was to each
surrounding cottage the embodied grandeur of that pride
of race which burned as strongly in the ploughman's
low-thatched roof as in the lofty baronial hall itself'.
This is a proposition that would be treated as laughable
by egalitarian reformers but the weight of evidence
supporting it is persuasive.
So now, as we watch the feudal system slip gently from
our view and into the pages of history, we can think of
future generations who will read the pages of that book
and wonder what it was like and why it lasted for so
long. I have tried to answer the first question already
so let us look at the second one. Feudalism in Scotland
survived for nine hundred years for one obvious reason -
because it worked. More importantly, while recognising
that injustice and inequality occurred, it survived
because it worked for most of the people most of the
time. Ultimately no system survives without the consent
of the people who are part of it and certainly not for
so long - Communism lasted for less than a hundred
years. As the 'Report on the Abolition of the Feudal
System' stated (1.7), feudalism 'could not have achieved
such success if it had not met the needs of the times in
an efficient way.' Indeed, not that long ago a
government White Paper* stated that 'there was no demand
of a modern industrial society that could not be met by
the feudal system of land tenure' (Sir Malcolm Innes of
Edingight, KCVO, 'The Baronage of Scotland: The History
of The Law of Succession and of The Law of Arms in
Relation Thereto', The Scottish Genealogist, June 2000).
On this basis I feel safe to say that we have now
dismantled something that we should have cherished;
something that, anachronistic as it might have been in
many ways (and what's wrong with a bit of anachronism
now and then), was ancient, honourable and just;
something that was colourful, interesting and romantic;
something that actually worked. And why did it work?
Because it was personal and familiar and small in scale.
The same could be said of the Scottish Regiments that
have been amalgamated or disbanded - and the Government
is at it again.
Is there a lesson here? Perhaps it is that what works
best, what people trust, what people will give their
time and effort (and sometimes their lives) for is
something that has stood the test of time, something
that is intimate and personal, something of which they
are part and which is part of them, like a family, a
village or a parish, all targets of the unsentimental
and unseeing eye of the reformer. Feudalism was just
that; it was a bond of service but it was a personal
bond and an honourable one. Goodbye, old friend.
*Land Tenure in Scotland: A Plan for Reform, Government
White Paper, Cm 4099, 1969
This
article was originally published in
The Scottish Genealogist
in September 2004,
by
Graham Senior-Milne.
|